Senegal 2017–It is all about 2019

Senegal holds assembly elections today, 30 July. Prime Minister Mahammed Boun Abdullah Dionne says: “We aren’t talking any longer about July 30, but of 2019.”

Of course. This is, after all, a counter-honeymoon election. It may not seem like it could be, because 2019 is pretty far off. But the presidential term is seven years, and the incumbent, Macky Sall, was elected in 2012.

In Votes from Seats (Chapter 12), Shugart and Taagepera (2017, in press) suggest that a counter-honeymoon election is any held three-fourths of the way through the president’s term. The months since the president was elected (first round in February, 2012) to now work out to 0.77. While there is no hard definition of when the counter-honeymoon starts–Elapsed Time between presidential elections is a continuous scale–three fourths is a reasonable approximation, and Senegal is just past that.

The main points Taagepera and I make about counter-honeymoon elections are: (1) The president’s party tends to suffer a substantial reduction in its vote share, and (2) They occur at a time when the parties are jockeying for position ahead of the next presidential election. It is the latter point that the premier is signaling is important today.

In the book, we have a formula for estimating the likely change in the president’s party’s support in a non-concurrent election (see my 23 April post from between rounds of the French presidential election). It is an empirical estimate, not a deductive model, but the pattern it captures has strong logic behind it, and it fits the data very well. It states:

Rp=1.20–0.725E,

where Rp is the vote share of the president’s party in the assembly election, divided by the president’s own vote share (in the first round, if two-round system), and E is the Elapsed Time (months between presidential and assembly election, divided by presidential inter-electoral period, also in months*).

In the case of today’s Senegal election, the equation returns a predicted value of Rp=0.64. Sall’s first-round vote percentage in 2012 was only 26.6%. It would be pretty bad news for him, and for governability in the final 23% of the time to the next presidential elections (19 months), if our equation’s application to today’s election turned out accurate. It would mean his party would get only 17% of the vote. Of course, the actual share could be higher. Or lower.

Attempting  to predict the votes in this case is also made more difficult by the fact that in the last assembly election, Sall’s party, the Alliance for the Republic (ARP) did not run on its own. It formed a coalition in advance of the election. That is not surprising–the electoral system is (unlike that of France) a single round, and it is quite majoritarian (like that of France). Thus there would be incentives for parties who had backed the newly elected president to join forces, and indeed they did. The last assembly election had a strong honeymoon timing, with E=0.06.

My quick search did not turn up any disaggregated votes by parties within the United in Hope coalition that was formed to support Sall in July, 2012. And I have no idea whether some of the parties that might have joined it have already jumped ship (the second point above about counter-honeymoon elections would lead me to expect a yes to that).

In the 2012 assembly election, United in Hope earned 53.06% of the vote, with runner-up Senegalese Democratic Party (PDS) way back, at 15.23%. The PDS was the party of the previous president, Abdoulaye Wade, whom Sall defeated. (Sall himself had won 65.8% in the runoff.) If that was a “normal” honeymoon, we would have expected the president’s party to have won 30.7%,  implying an additional 20% or so coming from other, post-first-round coalition partners.

The Wikipedia article on today’s election says that the coalition backing Sall includes the Socialist Party and the Alliance of the Forces of Progress. These parties’ candidates in the 2012 first round earned 11.3% and 13.2% of the votes, respectively. If we add those up we get 50.7%, which would actually imply little growth for the parties in the honeymoon election. (This is not surprising to me; the supporters of the defeated candidate would be harder to mobilize for a nonconcurent assembly election than for the presidential runoff.) However, perhaps we could use this revised figure in our Rp calculation. If we do, we get around 32% for their possible combined share, instead of 17% using only Sall’s own party. Anything much above 32% would defy the Elapsed Time expectations.

The Wikipedia article also says that the opposition failed to coordinate. The electoral system is mixed-member majoritarian. Around 40% of the seats are by PR (nationwide), with the rest in a mix of single-seat and multi-seat constituencies, using plurality (according to IPU). Thus even 32% against a divided opposition might leave the pro-Sall coalition near a majority of seats. But if his alliance is nearer 17%, governing could be difficult for the last quarter of his term.

The Senegalese system is semi-presidential, of the premier-presidential subtype. Thus the cabinet can fall if it lacks the confidence of the assembly majority, but the president has significant powers (he does not require an investiture vote to install the cabinet and he has a legislative veto). Cohabitation is a possibility, but so is a reshuffled pro-Sall cabinet.

_______

* In the book, we actually calculate E based off the precise date, but here I have just used whole months.

10 thoughts on “Senegal 2017–It is all about 2019

  1. Wikipedia says the pro-Sall coalition has secured 49.5% of the vote, and 125 seats of 165 (a reasonable result given the electoral system, which is MMM with 90 members elected using list plurality as the nominal tier). I don’t know why this is so substantially out of line with what Shugart’s formula projects, but it’s worth nothing that Sall’s 26.6% in the first round in 2012 became 65.8% in the second; perhaps there was an element of tactical voting in this election that was absent in the 2012 presidential first round?

    Like

  2. Well, assuming the election was fair (I have no reason to say it was not), the answer is one of two things: (1) there is a lot of government patronage spread around, which is a factor not accounted for by the formula; or (2) the formula isn’t predictive.

    Of course both can be true at the same time. And, in fact, Taagepera and I do not claim the formula predicts (despite my rather sloppy use of that term in the post), because we have no deductive logic for the specific coefficient values. But of the cases we were able to include (and I think one or two Senegalese elections are among them), there are no cases of Rp>1 for E>0.75. But strange things happen now and then…

    Like

  3. The degree of advantage for the winners is staggering, even for MMM. The PR tier isn’t doing much here, if the winning alliance can get 3/4 of seats on half the votes.

    I am actually not sure it is correct to call it MMM. The IPU seems to say that the non-PR tier is plurality list in those cases of multi-seat districts, not MNTV. If that is correct, it is not MMM, by definition, and it would indeed be even more majoritarian, because under MNTV it is at least possible that a popular local figure not from the dominant party could win a seat in a district here and there. Plurality list would rule that out.

    Like

    • Why should we be so restrictive in defining MMM? If Senegal’s list component were compensatory it would still be MMP; I don’t see why MMM with plurality list would make the system anything else than Mixed Member Majoritarian.

      Like

  4. The lower tier has 90 seats in 45 districts (range 1 – 7 seats) and is indeed closed list plurality. Closed list plurality (M>1) is not uncommon in French ex-colonies, see also Cameroon, Chad, Côte d’Ivoire, Djibouti and may be Gabon.
    I would call it MMM as soon as it combines independently a PR tier and a plurality/majority tier, even if the latter is not M=1 (see Massicotte & Blais, “Mixed electoal systems : a conceptual and empirical survey”, Electoral studies, 18 (1999) 341 who would call it “superposition”)

    Like

  5. I don’t really object to calling these systems MMM, for lack of a better term (and the desire not to invent new labels for every new combination). But strictly speaking, the “mixed” means nominal and list. It seems the “lower” tier is also list, rather than nominal, but certainly it is majoritarian.

    Like

  6. Senegal is president-parliamentary, not premier-presidential, according to Article 53, section 2 of the Constitution: “The Government conducts and coordinates the policy of the Nation under the direction of the Prime Minister. He is responsible before the President of the Republic and before the National Assembly under the conditions specified by Articles 85 and 86 of the Constitution.”

    Like

    • So, there is here a dual accountability of the cabinet, unlike it would happen in a premier-presidential system, where the government is solely accountable to the legislature, like in France or Portugal.

      Like

      • Also, the constitution says “The President of the Republic appoints the Prime Minister and terminates his functions.” The French constitution, on which the Senegalese is based, reads “The President of the Republic shall appoint the Prime Minister. He shall terminate the appointment of the Prime Minister when the latter tenders the resignation of the Government.”

        This would seem to back up Bruno’s argument above. From its constitution, Senegal does look president-parliamentary.

        Like

  7. Indeed, Robert Elgie on his recent books has been classifying Senegal as having the president-parliamentary subtype of semi-presidentialism, which can also be read on his own blog, as well.

    Like

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.